All Episodes

August 1, 2023 25 mins

Mia walks through some of the history and theory of landlords as a class and rent as a concept to explain why modern rents are so high.

Donate to the Burgerville Worker's Union Fund: bit.ly/burgerdefense

See omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.

Mark as Played
Transcript

Episode Transcript

Available transcripts are automatically generated. Complete accuracy is not guaranteed.
Speaker 1 (00:00):
Hi, this is Mia. So before we get to today's episode,
last Friday, the rank and file of the Burgerville Workers Union,
which is the country's first successful fast food union, went
on strike against a campaign of disciplinings and firings of
primarily trans and POC workers by the bosses who are
once again trying to crush the union. The strike has
worked so far, but they need support from the community

(00:23):
to help pay workers and help these people feed their
families so they can continue fighting the boss's capitalism and
building democracy in the workplace. You can go to Bitley's
Slash Burger Defense to do it. To their funds, we
will have links to that description. And yeah, thank you
all so much, and now on to the show. It's

(00:48):
it's a solo meda episode if it could happen here
the podcast where things fall apart and sometimes we've put
them back together. I'm your host, Mia Wong, and today
we're going to be talking about why the rent is
so high? Now, Okay, there's there's a lot of sort
of ways that you could in theory approach this question,
and I decided that I think one of the most

(01:10):
useful approaches to it is you take a sort of
a more a more sort of historical and theoretical approach.
And I think the start of any kind of sort
of theoretical approach to rent is by asking what rent
actually is. And the answer to this, and this is
something that is that is relatively consistent across most of

(01:31):
sort of classical political economy, and and you see this
in some of sort of geoclassical economics, is that the
thing that's special about rent is that rent, unlike you know,
anything else, is money that you get because you own something,
not because you you know, have produced anything. And this
means that you know, the landlord does not produce anything

(01:55):
of value at all. All they do is extract value
from other sectors of the economy. Now, this has a wide,
wide variety of sort of political and social effects. Mark
saw the landowning class as an obstacle to the development
of capitalism. And this is an idea. The idea of
that again, landowners specifically as a class that is different

(02:17):
from the sort of capitalist class or the working class,
hinders the growth of capitalism is an idea that a
lot of different people across the basically the entirety of
the political spectrum have shared at various times and this
causes some very very strange alliances. Particularly in places like
Latin America, you still have economies that are you know,

(02:40):
not entirely based, but economies that have enormous landowners who
drive sort of vast portions of both the economy and
of the sort of political process. And in Latin America,
and this is true in a lot of other places,
it was not uncommon for you to get what's known
as developmentalism, which is an ideology based on using essentially

(03:01):
protectionist measures, things like terroriffs, sometimes capital controls, restrictions on
kinds of investment that foreign companies can do. Sometimes I
mean just straight up the nationalization of natural resources in
order to develop an industrial economy. Now, developmentalism, as our
most sort of alliances against the land and elite, are
politically messy. It draws on a range of ideologies from

(03:25):
you know, like pretty right wing nationalists, some very very
very scary people technically developmentalists, to liberal and also centrisfactions
whose sort of productive and social base is in a
specific kind of sort of domestic capitalists who's interested in
sort of producing stuff locally, and also to people like

(03:46):
Bolivia's Evo Morales, who is you know, broadly considered a socialist,
although I think his commitment to anything like socialist politics
is tenuous at best. But all of these sort of
political groups can and do, and have various times work together.
So this is actually one of the bases of Morales
as well. I guess it's not really Moralysis Party anymore.
But even Morales's MS, which was a very sort of

(04:11):
explicit alliance between sort of left wing social movements and
then more sort of moderate centrist factions who were effectively developmentalist.
This is a sort of a representation of a very
common like kind of developmentalist politics, which is again this
alliance between sort of left and capitalist factions who ally
gets like large landowners on the basis that feudalism, which

(04:33):
is which is usually the way that like the sort
of the power of large landowners is conceived, is an
enemy to both of them. Now, this isn't how sort
of develop like states that use developmentalist strategies have to work. Germany,
for example, uses a lot of developmentalist techniques to industrialize
in the late eighteen hundreds. But you know, the old
landowning class, the old sort of like like German aristocracy,

(04:56):
is allied with the capitalists in Germany and the to
you know, the two classes, the sort of German aristocracy
and the capital's class effectively birge. On the other hand,
landowning classes are often implacably hostile to industrialization, and countries
that essentially annihilated the landowning classes by carrying out land
reform tend to perform better economically than their counterparts who

(05:18):
left a landowning class intact, which contributed to the enormous
success of the economies of countries like China and Japan,
Taiwan and Vietnam, who, despite their enormous sort of ideological
and political differences, all carried out land reform in the
twentieth century were rewarded with eventually by very very powerful
and large scale industrial economies. But you know, you might
be saying, ya, you've kind of put the cart in

(05:40):
front of the horse here. You've talked about, you know,
you've gone into some of the sort of political effects
of rent first, but you haven't actually, you know, explained
how rent actually works. And so that is what I'm
going to do next. And to explain how rent works,

(06:00):
I'm going to turn to an unusual source, the work
of the Great Venezuela and anthropologist Fernando Corneal. Corneal' is
a fascinating character. He studied anthropology at my alma mater,
the University of Chicago under Terrence Turner, a guy who
I think ninety nine percent people have never heard of before,
but is probably most famous now for being also you know,

(06:21):
also teaching David Graeber and being a sort of major
influence on his work now. Unlike David Graber. While Corneal
was at the University of Chicago, he tried to get
permission from the Cuban government to go do field work
in Cuba, and you know, so he gets to Cuba
and he's like negotiating with the government and the government
tells him to fuck off. So okay, he tries to
go back to the US. But Immigration and Nationalization Services,

(06:45):
the i INS, which is basically the predecessor of like
Immigration Services ICE in the Border Patrol i INS was
sort of dissolved in two thousand and three when the
sort of like I don't know exactly what the technical
term for it is, but with the consolidation of of
the Department of Homeland Security, which is really truly a
thing that I think we tend to think it was

(07:05):
only present, but is actually about twenty years old, and
I am older than it was. Also, you know, this
sort of outside the episode is like an enormously fascist
institution that centralized an enormous amount of sort of political
power in these like terrifying surveillance and police bureaucracies. But

(07:26):
you know, okay, so they're back back back back to
the Fernandic coordineal story. So he guys to go back
to the US, but Ans, which is the predecessory for
all this stuff, like arrest him immediately and they deport
him and ban him from the US on the grounds
that he was that they suspected him of being a
quote subversive agent. Now, and again I cannot emphasize this enough.

(07:52):
The sequence of events here is that he tries to
go to Cuba and the Cuban government tells him to
fuck off, and so he goes back to the US
and the US government is like, oh, yeah, no, this
guy through the Cuban government just refused to let to
do field work. This this this guy is definitely a
Cuban agent. So his entire sort of like life gets

(08:14):
derailed by this. He wants up I think back in
Venezuela for a while. I think it takes like twenty
almost like twenty years for him to be able to
get back to the US and finish his PhD. But
you know, when he does and sort of be in
the process of this, he becomes a very very famous,
as well respected anthropologist. Now when now was it you Chicago,

(08:35):
like all of the people who sort of trained Corneal
that that whole generation and really like the whole sort
of school of anthropology that he came from, which is
a very very interesting school that if if you want
to like read about this kind of stuff, I read
David Graeber's Towards an Anthopological Theory of Value. I might
do an episode on it at some point later, but
all of that stuff is gone. But but I ran

(08:57):
into a professor who knew him back in the day,
and he told us that Corneil was. You know, on
the one hand, very is back to the academic like
very sort of like upstanding, like member of the academic
communitee also incredibly popular as like a partier who just
get absolutely wasted and start dancing on tables. This guy
absolutely rips, you know, and I think a very few

(09:20):
people outside of anthropology you've ever heard of him. But
in anthropology, Corneil is important enough to like, if you're
right about the state, you at least have to like
mention him. And you know, that doesn't necessarily mean that,
like most of the people who say the words that
the Magical State, which is the name of his sort
of famous book, actually have read it. But I did
read this book. I've read this book multiple times and

(09:43):
it's really really interesting. Now. The Magical State, Nature, Money,
and Majority in Venezuela is probably most famous as a
history of the Venezuelan state, but that doesn't mean that
it's sort of exclusively about that history, and in fact,
you know it, it really can't be. In order to

(10:04):
think about the Venezuelan state, you have to think about oil.
But you also can't think about oil in the way
that most histories of oil think about it, which is
a story about sort of like high geopolitics. Right. If
you look at the history of oil, right, it's about
like high geopolitics and like prospecting and like trekking oil

(10:27):
prices over time, and you know, the sort of most
famous book in this genre is Daniel Jurgen's The Prize,
which is a fine book, but it shares in this
sort of tendency to you know, kind of you know,
unless they're writing about like a guy going prospecting, right,
there's this tendency to sort of ignore the sort of
material characteristics of oil and the sort of political effects

(10:50):
of the extraction process, and a lot of other aspects
of oil that are very very important. And what Corineal
realizes is that oil is intricately tied to sort of
the political conception of nature, to systems of landownership, and
also to Venezuelan state craft. Now this may seem a

(11:12):
bit far afield, but in order to understand oil, you
have to think about rent and rent extraction. And that's
what Corneal does in ways that are both sort of
profoundly interesting and I think, in a lot of ways
profoundly ahead of his time. So Corneal, like us, asked

(11:38):
the question what actually is rent? Now? For you know,
Corneal goes through rent and a lot you know, and
it like goes through what you could, I guess called
economic history of concessions of rent, right, starting with the
classical economists. Uh, we're not that interested in the classical
economists because quite frankly, if you're if I don't know,

(12:01):
if you're running into a neo Ricardian analysis of what
rent is like I don't know, you're you're already a specialist,
like stuff is stuff, stuff is happening for you, thus
quite interesting, quite odd, but where we're mostly going to
ignore them because the original classical economists' work has it's
it's largely not the way people think about this now,

(12:24):
and to the extent that people sort of claim to
be derivatives of like these people that people claiming the
lineage of Adam Smith, like, eh, that's kind of sketchy.
Is that we're going to turn to Corneal's analysis of
the way that neoclassical economics thinks about rent. Now. Corneal

(12:44):
someone who has spent a lot of time in the
sort of literature of like oil pricing and sort of
theories the sort of price formation and the state of
the market or the effect of political actors on it,
et cetera, et cetera, et cetera, and he argues that
there's basically two ways of thinking about rent. In terms
of a commodity like oil. There is a macroeconomics view

(13:06):
in which the rent someone who owns oil extracts when
people have to buy it from them, you know. Okay,
so like like if if if you're a landowner, right,
you get rent because you own the thing, and then
people have to like take it like people need it.
You have it, so you get to extract rent from
it just by virtue sort of having it in the
in the microeconomics view, when someone like pays the rent, right,

(13:33):
what that is is they're paying for what's called natural
capital or capital that's you know, provided by nature that
someone now owns through like the miracle of private property.
And so for these people, rent isn't something that's extracted
at all. Right, it's just someone getting paid for their capital.
Because the way that they think about, you know, about

(13:53):
something like oil, is that they think oil is just
sort of natural capital. Now, okay, it's like this is
this is in some sense, you know, I was like, okay,
who cares about this? This is kind of like this this
seems very obvious. But there's also a macroeconomics perspective which
is very different. And the macroeconomics perspective holds that you know,

(14:14):
rent isn't a payment for capital at all. It's something
paid to landowners by capitalists, and the rent that these
landowners get is basically the difference between you know, what
it costs you to get the oil out of the
you use sort of the landowner to get the oil
out of the ground, and what it costs the person
who has the highest price of production to get the
oil out of the ground. Now, okay, for reasons that

(14:37):
are very complicated that I can't get into here, basically,
the person who is like the worst at getting oil
out of the ground is the person who sets what
the price of oil is. So you know, the sort
of like highest possible extraction price tends to be the price.
And then you know, the micro the sort of macroeconomic
analysis of what rent is, right is that it's a

(15:01):
thing that capitalists pay to landowners who own natural resources,
and the amount of money they get is based on
how much cheaper it is for like that you know,
that landlord to get their oil out of the ground
than it is for like the landlord who's like the
worst at this. And this is a real question, right.
The question is is someone who's getting rent paid to them,

(15:22):
is that rent payment for capital that they own, or
is it money from capitalists that capitalists have to pay
to a non capitalist class. And Corneal's answer is like, well,
obviously rent is distracted from cirplus value because because landowners
don't produce value. But there's two different sort of places
that they can get this value from. And this is

(15:45):
where we have to get into something that's kind of weird,
and that is the two different kinds of rents. But okay,
before we get into the two kinds of different rents,
do you know what else? There's two different kinds of Yeah,
that's right. It is the products and services that support
this show. And we're back. I hope you have enjoyed

(16:14):
both of the different kinds of products and services that
support the show. And okay, I promise you two kinds
of rents, and I'm now going to give you two
kinds of rent. So the two kinds of rent, there
is something called differential rent, and differential rent is kind
of close to the sort of macrocive we talked about earlier.

(16:36):
So differential rent is rent that's set by the price
of production on the market right now, as we sort
of mentioned, prices tend towards the highest price of production.
It's set by the people who are worse of producing it.
And differential rent is the rent that the rest of
the market gets by costing it by you know, by
it costing less for them to extract oil than it does,

(16:57):
you know for someone who's like the worst at extracting oil.
Corneil explains this in terms of it. For a long time,
the US was sort of the price leader of oil,
and it was the price leader of oil because the
American like property right system is so absolutely bonkers that
it makes it really really hard. You have to like

(17:17):
you have to like individually negotiate with like every person
who owns a cow pasture a Nebraska in order to
sort of like extract oil from them. And this makes
the production process like very expensive. And so everyone else
in the world is getting this differential rent because they
have like a less completely like just wild system of property.

(17:39):
So the product of this is that everyone else is
getting differential rent because it's way cheaper for them to
produce oil than it is for the US to produce oil.
So differential rent is a product of your efficiency, right.
It's how it's an amount of money that's based on
sort of the price of oil, and it's based on
how much better, you know, because you're st selling the
oil at like the same price, right, But the amount

(17:59):
that you get, you know, the amount of rent that
you get, is the difference between how much it costs
you to get this oil out of the ground and
how much it costs like some sort of American dip
shit you as to spend all this time negotiating with
like thirty thousand individual landowners in the US to do it.
So that that's differential rents. But there's also something called

(18:21):
absolute rent. Now, absolute rent is very, very very different
from from differential rent because absolute rent is not really
determined by sort of production prices or like the market
or supply and demand at all. Absolute rent is determined
by the social power of the landowner. And this has

(18:42):
really interesting effects, right because again absolute rent isn't based
on the production process and is instead based on you know,
the social it's it's it's a social product of power
and this, you know, this, this means that landlords and
rent extractors can do something that capitalists aren't supposed to

(19:02):
be able to do. They can get profits that are
larger than the general rate of profit, and they can
do it just by virtue of being powerful and owning land.
And this has a bunch of very very weird knock
on effects. Right. If you've ever seen landlords talk about rent, right,
you've seen the consequences of this. These people genuinely believe
that they have a sort of moral right to returns

(19:24):
with no risk all of the time, and that all
of society should be structured in such a way as
to guarantee that they have this free income that they
do fucking nothing to do other than own buildings, and
it should be guaranteed, you know, it should be structured
to guarantee this by forcing tenants to pay rent no literally,
no matter what is happening, you know, like regardless of shit,

(19:45):
like I don't know, a pandemic. Now. The other sort
of important difference is that is that absolute rent does
not obey the laws of supply and demand. It is
a product of social power, you know, it's the power
of land ownership itself health, and it's also sort of
the power you know that the social power is. It's
not just purely the product of light ownership. It's also

(20:06):
a product of the organization of the land owning class
and the extent to which they're backed by the state
and you know, a sort of militaries as polices, and
this causes economists who are attempting to use supply and
demand to explain rent to get very very important events
very wrong. One of the things that Corneal points out

(20:27):
is that Maurice Aidelman, who is a very very famous
oil economist, predicts in nineteen seventy two that the price
of oil is going to collapse based on oversupply and competition. Instead,
the price of oil between nineteen seventy three and nineteen
seventy four increases by four hundred percent because oil produces

(20:48):
banned together to exercise their power, and this organization, known
as OPEK becomes a genuine world power. Here's here's how
Corneil puts it. The sharp inc of nineteen seventy three
and nineteen seventy four in oil prices did not result
from a world shortage of oil. It was rather the
outcome of a long historical process by which OPEC nations,

(21:11):
acting as landowners, developed the means to extract a rent
on the basis of their ownership of the oil fields,
an absolute rent in addition to the differential rents they
had collected in the past. In nineteen seventy three, a
seat of converging political and economic conditions helped establish their
collective ability to restrict the world's supply of oil. With

(21:33):
this power, Opek felt entitled to set my market prices
of oil, thus freeing the level of rent from the
previous constraint of the market price. Now, rent itself, absolute
and differential would come to determine the market price of oil.
Now you may be asking yourself, VIIa, that this is
all well and good for describing the price of how

(21:57):
for describing how the price of oil changes? But what
does this have to do with me? And the answer
is that while Corneal is specifically focused on resource rents
for obvious reasons, he is doing a study of the
state of Venezuela, you can apply his analysis to the
kind of rent that we all pay. If you follow
Corneal's conclusions about absolute rent through to the American rental market,

(22:20):
it produces startlingly different conclusions about the source and sort
of nature of the so called housing crisis that are
traditionally presented. If rent levels are a product of the
social power of the landlord class, the behavior that's otherwise
inexplicable like landlords sitting on empty properties instead of renting
an amount at lower rates, suddenly become clear armed with

(22:41):
the backing of the state's secure at social power by
carrying out evictions, and with the state's implicit backing to
carry out technically illegal evictions, landlords can extract both differential
and absolute rents, allowing them to tell the market to
take a hike as setting ever increasing rents that renters
have no choice but to pay or be swept decided
in brutal anti homeless rays. This has massive consequences on

(23:05):
any potential strategy to reduce rent. Opek, remember, was able
to use its social power to increase the price of
oil by four hundred percent, even in a period where
the actual supply of oil was enormous, by pure virtue
of organization and the power of their landownership. While American
landlords is certainly weaker and less organized than Opek, their
social power is still such that increasing supply is not

(23:27):
guaranteed to drive down prices, because in a situation governed
by the extraction of absolute rent, rent is not determined
by prices. Prices are determined by rent. On the other hand,
this means that you can reduce rent by breaking the
social power of the landlord. And indeed, even in very
hot housing markets like Toronto and Los Angeles, this strategy

(23:50):
canon has worked. Tenets. Unions which deploy the power of
collective bargaining and the social solidarity of renters to combat
the power of landlords, have succeeded in reducing rents and
can and will continue to do so. But these efforts
are only the beginning of a process that finally answers
the question why are rents so high? If rents are

(24:12):
high because of the social power of landlords, the way
to bring rents down is to crush the batters completely
and appropriate them, to seize every last building and plot
of land from every landlord in the country and drive
them as a class from the political mainstream into the
pages of history. And then, and this is crucial, not
to replace them with another landowning class, or, as Leninist
proposed that it actually did replace them with the state.

(24:34):
Only by destroying the category of landlord, not by regulating
it or nationalizing it, can we finally escape the long
nightmare of rents and enter a world where people's ability
to live is determined not by the sort of capricious
and arbitrary will of a small class of landowners, but
on their human need for housing. This has been It

(24:54):
could happen here. You can find us in the usual places,
and yeah, go go into the worlds and make the
world without rent to reality. It could happen here as
a production of cool Zone Media. For more podcasts from
cool Zone Media, visit our website coolzonemedia dot com, or

(25:16):
check us out on the iHeartRadio app, Apple Podcasts, or
wherever you listen to podcasts. You can find sources for
It could Happen Here, updated monthly at coolzonemedia dot com
slash sources. Thanks for listening.

It Could Happen Here News

Advertise With Us

Follow Us On

Hosts And Creators

Robert Evans

Robert Evans

Garrison Davis

Garrison Davis

James Stout

James Stout

Show Links

About

Popular Podcasts

On Purpose with Jay Shetty

On Purpose with Jay Shetty

I’m Jay Shetty host of On Purpose the worlds #1 Mental Health podcast and I’m so grateful you found us. I started this podcast 5 years ago to invite you into conversations and workshops that are designed to help make you happier, healthier and more healed. I believe that when you (yes you) feel seen, heard and understood you’re able to deal with relationship struggles, work challenges and life’s ups and downs with more ease and grace. I interview experts, celebrities, thought leaders and athletes so that we can grow our mindset, build better habits and uncover a side of them we’ve never seen before. New episodes every Monday and Friday. Your support means the world to me and I don’t take it for granted — click the follow button and leave a review to help us spread the love with On Purpose. I can’t wait for you to listen to your first or 500th episode!

24/7 News: The Latest

24/7 News: The Latest

The latest news in 4 minutes updated every hour, every day.

Crime Junkie

Crime Junkie

Does hearing about a true crime case always leave you scouring the internet for the truth behind the story? Dive into your next mystery with Crime Junkie. Every Monday, join your host Ashley Flowers as she unravels all the details of infamous and underreported true crime cases with her best friend Brit Prawat. From cold cases to missing persons and heroes in our community who seek justice, Crime Junkie is your destination for theories and stories you won’t hear anywhere else. Whether you're a seasoned true crime enthusiast or new to the genre, you'll find yourself on the edge of your seat awaiting a new episode every Monday. If you can never get enough true crime... Congratulations, you’ve found your people. Follow to join a community of Crime Junkies! Crime Junkie is presented by audiochuck Media Company.

Music, radio and podcasts, all free. Listen online or download the iHeart App.

Connect

© 2025 iHeartMedia, Inc.