Episode Transcript
Available transcripts are automatically generated. Complete accuracy is not guaranteed.
Speaker 1 (00:00):
Hey, they're Odd Lots listeners. The following episode was recorded
May second on the Princeton campus. Obviously, some things have
changed since then, but I still think it's a very
interesting and relevant conversation, So take a listen.
Speaker 2 (00:17):
Bloomberg Audio Studios, Podcasts, Radio News.
Speaker 1 (00:33):
Hello and welcome to another episode of the Odd Lots Podcast.
I'm Tracy Alloway.
Speaker 3 (00:37):
And I'm Joe Wisenthal.
Speaker 1 (00:38):
Joe, do you feel like you are hearing the term
exorbitant privilege a lot more than you used to?
Speaker 3 (00:46):
Yes?
Speaker 1 (00:47):
Is that a loaded question? Maybe it is.
Speaker 3 (00:49):
Yes, you heard it a lot.
Speaker 4 (00:51):
You know, large budget deficits, right, those were explainable or
people claimed that they were explainable because of something called
exorbitant privilege. I've never totally known what that term means,
but obviously with some of the policy volatility in the
United States, which is a very nice way of putting it,
you hear it again and whether it can last or
whether it could be exhausted.
Speaker 1 (01:10):
So I had the same reaction to you. I started
thinking about it, like, why are we hearing this over
and over again? And then I was curious when we
first started using that term, and I think to your
point about what exactly this means. We first started using
it in the nineteen sixties and sort of going into
the early nineteen seventies. Yes, And it was this idea
that because we had built the financial system around the
(01:33):
US dollar visa vi Bretton Woods, which we've talked about
on the show, that the US was in this privileged
position where it felt like people in other countries were
basically subsidizing the US lifestyle.
Speaker 4 (01:46):
The constraints that typical countries might face in terms of
spending don't to the same extent seem to apply to
the United States in general. When it comes to talk
about the dollar, I find that there's just a lot
of slaty definitions thrown around. People will talk about dollar strength,
but they're not always clear whether they're talking about dollar
euro as an exchange rate, or dollars share of transactions,
(02:09):
or dollar share of reserves or the global reserve current
scare the global safe haven assets. Lots of fuzzy defined
terms that I'm satisfied that's totally fair.
Speaker 1 (02:18):
I don't get as mad at fuzzy terms because we
don't have all day like do we have to define
everything into like obsolescence? No, But anyway, speaking of someone
who probably also doesn't like fuzzy terms. To your point,
we have the perfect guest, yes, to talk about all
of this, and I guess a big moment that keeps
coming up on our show quite a few times over
recent episodes, and that is the Nixon Shock.
Speaker 4 (02:40):
The Nixon shock, right, because people look at the tariffs
that Trump announced on April second, and you reach for
historical analogies about the changing relationship between the US and
the rest of the world, and part via trade and
part via currency, and so much to mine from the past.
Speaker 1 (02:56):
So we have the perfect guest, and we're actually at
the perfect event to do this as well. So we're
at Princeton University.
Speaker 3 (03:02):
That's right. We came down here.
Speaker 4 (03:04):
We did a podcast which either if you're listening to this,
either it's going to come out or you'll have already
heard it, depending on the sequence. We're at a conference.
Brendan Greeley invited us down a conference on currencies and
what is a currency and.
Speaker 1 (03:17):
So forth, how to write a biography of a currency.
Speaker 4 (03:19):
That's the name of the conference. So anyway, yes, perfect guest,
at the perfect context to talk about the dollar.
Speaker 1 (03:24):
Okay, so we do have the perfect guest. We're going
to be speaking with He's a long time out lots guest, Yes,
although he hasn't been on for a while. Yeah, we're
speaking with Perry Marling, a professor of international political economy
at the Party School of Global Studies over at Boston University. Perry,
thank you for coming back on the show.
Speaker 5 (03:41):
Happy to be here.
Speaker 3 (03:42):
Great to catch up with you in person.
Speaker 1 (03:44):
Okay, I'm just going to jump in with the exorbitant
privilege question, because this keeps coming up. Is the US
dollar's role in the global financial system a net positive
or a net negative for the country?
Speaker 5 (03:58):
Well, I guess it depends on who you ask. This
exorbitant privileged thing, Okay, was coming from Europe. Okay, so
clearly Europe France in particular was viewing this as a
net positive for the United States and negative for themselves.
But in the United States there was coming to be
a view that it was a net negative, that it
(04:19):
was exorbitant burden, and that in fact, that something about
being the international reserve currency was getting in the way
of our manufacturing development and overvaluing our exchange rate. And
that became a theory that was accepted by the political forces.
Speaker 1 (04:35):
Just to be clear, we're talking in the nineteen sixties.
Was the French politician I think who first said that term.
Speaker 5 (04:41):
I think it was your scar tost name. But the
important point is that the view from one side of
the Atlantic and the view from the other side of
the Atlantic were quite different. So yes, let me take
you back to the sixties, okay. One way to understand
Bretton Woods ninety forty four, okay, was that this was
a pass off from Sterling pre World War One to
the dollar to build the post World War two international
(05:04):
monetary system. Okay, And so the bankers in New York thought, oh,
that's just great. You know, New York will become like London.
London had been the center of the world money market,
the center of the world capital market with Stirling before
World War One, and all the bankers knew that, and
they had been chomping in the bit to do this
for a long time. Okay. So that's what they thought
they were doing in building up during the fifties. But
(05:26):
in the sixties there started to be political resistance in
the United States, and the United States government started to
put taxes on people who came from abroad to float bonds.
And they tried to prevent it from happening. They tried
to prevent from happening. This is sort of American politics
that Americans are very suspicious of finance probably you know that, Okay.
Speaker 1 (05:46):
Especially globalist finance here.
Speaker 5 (05:48):
Yes, right, yeah, And so there came to be some
view that this was very bad for America, you know,
to have and so they tried to kill the private
capital markets throughout the sixties. Okay, there were various interventions,
and I go through in my book on Kinderberger. But
the danoument of all of this was nineteen seventy one. Okay,
August fifteenth, actually nineteen seventy one, when Richard Nixon took
(06:09):
the dollar off gold, which was the promise that had
been made at Bretton Woods, and increased tariffs by ten percent.
This was intended as leverage for forcing our allies to
revalue their currencies. So if you have the view that
the dollar is overvalued because it's a reserve currency, you
can force your allies to revalue their currency. So that happened.
Actually in December of that same year, nineteen seventy one,
(06:32):
the en went up and there wasn't euro then you know,
this was this. So this is August fifteenth, nineteen seventy one. Okay.
The reason I go through this in some detail is
that I think that the current events, the events of
the last is it only two months.
Speaker 3 (06:45):
Okay, yeah, two months, yeah, are.
Speaker 5 (06:49):
Quite analogous to what is going on, okay. And in fact,
some of the theories that were around back then have
been re emerged, you know, And so it's as if
no time has gone by. Okay, Trump is replaying the
Nixon Handbook, but times ten, because he's doing much more tariffs.
Of course, the world is much bigger than this was
really just a US versus Europe spat, okay, you know,
(07:11):
even you know, getting Japan to revalue was not such
a big Japan was not a big player yet in
nineteen seventy one, you know, Europe was the main object
of this, and the pound, sterling and the French franc
and the Deutsch mark, you know, there were separate currencies
at that time. They had the euro had not just happened.
So the world is now much more global, and so
it's quite a different kind of a shock. It's a
(07:32):
much more comprehensive shock.
Speaker 4 (07:34):
I think Nixon Playbook times ten is a very promising headline.
Speaker 1 (07:38):
I literally just read it.
Speaker 3 (07:40):
I know it is a very.
Speaker 4 (07:40):
Promising headline for this episode. I'm just curious the premise
that the dollar is this global reserve asset lead to
an overvaluation. You know, a country cares about overvaluation because
it wants to have competitive exports, or that seems to
be won't there does that actually bear out in the fact,
because when I you know, as I sort of said
in the intro, you could talk about a dollar strength
(08:02):
in terms of its reserve status or trade status or
dollar yen, dollar euro, is there actually a stable relationship
between the dollar share of X versus the exchange rate.
Speaker 5 (08:17):
Well, this is a debate among economists, and there's empirical
studies on both sides. I incline to say no, okay,
and in particular no now okay, because so much of
the dollar system is offshore, so you can get dollar
reserves if you want, you know, by having a euro
(08:37):
dollar deposit in France. You know that is not touching
the US shores at all. So some of this argument,
you know, is outdated. You know that the the globalization
of the dollar, the fact that the US refused to
make New York into London has led the world to
become a dollar system. And so I don't know that
those arguments work quite so well. I'm not sure those
(08:59):
people who are making them, you know, have paid attention
to the way in which the world has changed since
nineteen seventy one.
Speaker 1 (09:05):
Well, speaking of what changed after nineteen seventy one, there's
one more historical question that I want to ask you,
and please forgive me for not remembering this from your book,
But Charles Kindelberger, what did he think was going to
happen after Nixon unveiled all his policies.
Speaker 5 (09:22):
So he was very worried about this because he had
just finished this book, The World in Depression. Okay. That
made the argument that when Sterling was forced off gold, okay,
in September of nineteen thirty one, Okay, that the failure
to do the pass off to the dollar at that
time meant that there was no world currency, and so
(09:43):
there was a collapse of world trade and we had
world depression. Okay. And the reason he calls it the
crime of nineteen seventy one is that, in fact, the
US was not forced off of gold. This was a
decision by the president to just abrogate these agreements. So
he felt this was a fail of responsibility that was
just wrongheaded, and it came out of nowhere and there
(10:04):
was no reason to do this. But Nixon was very
clear about this that he saw the dollar system emerging
and he just wanted to kill it. And it was
America first, and he wanted to kill it. And as
I said, the bankers wouldn't let him. But that's a
little bit longer a story.
Speaker 1 (10:17):
But that's not what happened. We didn't have deflation. We
had inflation in the mid nineteen seventies, and we saw
the rest of the financial system sort of expand to
absorb what had been lost through the Nixon crime. I'm
doing air quotes here.
Speaker 3 (10:31):
He certainly didn't kill the dollar system.
Speaker 5 (10:33):
He did not kill the dollar system. It took a
while to put it back together again. I grew up
in the seventies. I think I'm a little older than you.
I was in high school in the seventies, and it
was not a pleasant time to be alive. Stagflation You've
heard the words stagflation, so where you have unemployment and
inflation at the same time, and it was about there
was a breakdown of the international monitor system. The story.
(10:53):
The important date for that is maybe in nineteen seventy three,
because I haven't filled in the rest of it that
after the stabilization of exchange rates in December of nineteen
seventy one, the revaluation of the end, as I say,
Nixon took advantage of that new fixed exchange rate to
try to get himself re elected by leaning on the
FED to lower interest rates. And the Fed did lower
(11:14):
interest rates, but the rest of the world did not.
And so now you have a real problem because with
the fixed exchange rate, you have free money by borrowing
in dollars at a low rate and lending in deutsch
marks in Germany, and the Central Bank of Germany has
to defend the exchange rate, and so they have to
absorb all of this, and they did until they couldn't
(11:34):
or decided not to, And so after seventy three there
was dis floating exchange rates. And so I think that
is a kind of incipient breakdown of the international monetary
system where you don't have stable exchange rates. And Kimderberger
thought that that could be a replay of the hot
money periods of the nineteen thirties, where speculators would say
I need to be safe, Oh, I should be in
(11:56):
the pound sterling, and then they would say, no, I
think maybe the pounds sterling is going to devalue to
be in the French franc No. And in as consequence,
they're destabilizing all the exchange rates. And with the exchange
rates fluctuating like that, how can you plan. So it
basically broke down capitol flows, short term capital flows, long
term capital flows trade. So the whole thing broke down,
and so he was afraid that that would happen. But
(12:18):
it didn't happen because the bankers wouldn't let it. And
in particular, the BIS played an important role in providing
currency swaps for countries that were under attack. They were
taking the opposite side of some of these trades, and
gradually we built what we now experience as the offshore
dollar system, where there's dollars borrowing and lending offshore doesn't
touch New York at all. That happened during the nineteen
(12:40):
seventies as a consequence of these policy actions in seventy
one and seventy three, and by nineteen seventy nine when
Vulcar comes. This is the time when the United States
is now taking responsibility again, okay, and you now have
the infrastructure, you know where it is offshore. Okay, so
maybe it's more politically acceptable than it was in the sixties.
(13:01):
And then we go to the races. You know, it
takes a little while for the you know, go to
the races. Do double digit interest rates at twenty percent
interest rates? I remember that too, you know, I was
in college then and taking out student loans, and so
it wasn't until nineteen eighty five at Plaza where the
rest of the world sort of they actually agreed to
some parodies and so forth. But the system got put
back together again. That's the story, and I think maybe
(13:25):
that's a hopeful story for this moment, the Nixon playbook.
Speaker 4 (13:45):
Before we get to the current moment. This is just
a theoretical question. When you look at the world economy,
either in the past or specifically now, does it inevitably
tend towards sort of like one dominant currency. I mean,
you know, and there's obviously countries hold other currencies too.
They hold euros, and theyailed some Swiss frank probably and
maybe a little gold, et cetera. But is there a
(14:07):
tendency towards like a power law distribution where one typically
becomes the currency, kind of like in social networking, it's
like there's Facebook.
Speaker 5 (14:16):
I don't think that's the right analogy power law distribution.
I know what you're talking about. There. There is a tendency,
but it comes from sort of efficiency in exchange.
Speaker 3 (14:24):
Okay.
Speaker 5 (14:25):
Kinderberger always made the analogy that before we had the FED,
there was not park clearing between California and New York, right,
So that was itself a sort of tax on trade
inside the United States, and you weren't really sure how
it was going to work, and there wasn't par check
clearing and so forth. With the creation of the FED
and with war finance, that all went away and we
got park clearing. So he was always impressed by the analogy.
(14:47):
If this was a good idea for the United States,
maybe we should do this for the world as well.
And he saw, as I said, this hot money. When
you have multiple key currencies, you are inviting speculation, so
your de stateabilizing the exchange rates, and therefore that's the
tax on trade and on capitol flows. You don't want
to do that, Okay. Now, the analogy with the United States,
(15:07):
you know, in retrospect went too far because he was
a big advocate of fixed exchange rates, and it seems
like that's a bridge too far, that's too that's too demanding.
So we do not have fixed exchange rates. We have
managed floating exchange rates that are that are managed through
joint intervention of of sort of the Club of six,
the major central banks. This is another Kinderberger point that
(15:29):
if you stabilize the core of the system, then you
stabilize the system as a whole. That there will always
be countries that are facing crises and so forth, but
as long as you stabilize the core, you'll be all right.
The system is as a whole will be all right.
That's why the global financial crisis was such a problem,
because that came from the core. It threatened the core.
You may remember where I don't know if you were
(15:50):
doing odd lots yet then quite but I was. You're
a financial journalist, and you know that they thought the
world was going to come to an end and that
was the end of the dollar and all of that.
But in fact, that's what happened, was the expansion of
the dollar system to the global South. Because of zero
interest rates in the North. And so this offshore dollar
system that, as I was saying, it was given a
(16:10):
big boost by the Nixon Shock of nineteen seventy one.
In retrospect, as I say, it was not pleasant to
live through, Okay, was given a big boost by the
global financial crisis. Okay, and now we have the Trump shock. Okay,
that's happening. And so I think that the lesson of
history may be that the bankers won't let them, you
know that. But it's going to be painful, it's not
(16:32):
going to be pleasant. But I do not think that
the dollar system is going away.
Speaker 1 (16:38):
I guess the obvious question to ask after that is, Okay,
we have these other moments in time where there was
a crisis in the dollar system, and yet it came
back stronger. And I guess the question is is Trump
different to the policymakers that were in charge at that
particular time. He seems much more interested and willing in
(16:59):
try buying very very new things and potentially destroying some
really really big things. Is he going to want to
maintain that system? I'm thinking, you know, something specific like
the dollar swap lines. You can imagine the headlines if
the FED is extending billions of dollars to Europe or something.
Imagine how Trump would feel about headlines about Americans bailing
(17:20):
out Europe or something like that.
Speaker 5 (17:22):
Yes, so this is another thing that is different today
than it was back then. As I say, Arthur Burns
caved in to mister Nixon, helped him try to get reelected.
Economists know this, and it was a shameful episode at
the FED. You know that that should never be so,
that should never be. So. So what we're seeing play
(17:44):
out right now is quite a different drama. Okay, Mister
Powell is not caving in. Mister Powell is very publicly
going and saying that equidity swap lines are in place,
and I am not lowering interest rates, okay until I
see that the inflationary effects of these tariffs are not
going to undermine our economy. And so there is a conflict, okay,
(18:05):
that is developing. There an immovable object facing an irresistible force. Okay.
And so it's just started. It's just started. But that's
very different from ninety seventy one, okay. And the other
thing that's different from ninety seventy one is that the
apparatus of the offshore dollar system is up and running, right.
It does. You don't have to create it. It exists.
(18:25):
It exists already, and I'm sure it's being put into
force already that you can move a lot of this
stuff offshore, Okay, and you will. It is a little
peculiar that we're talking about. It's a globalized financial world,
the extent to which is a global world is much
more true in finance than it is in trade, notwithstanding
(18:46):
global supply chains and everything like that. But you know,
it takes a long time to get a car from
China to New York, you know, through the Panama Canal
or whatever. It doesn't take any time for money to
flow this way and that way. So and they're not
putting any tariffs on capital flows. They're not putting it.
So the financial system is not being threatened, this financial
(19:09):
system that grew up over this period. Maybe I shouldn't
give them any ideas well.
Speaker 1 (19:14):
I mean there's some discussion. Is that the possibility?
Speaker 2 (19:17):
Yeah?
Speaker 1 (19:17):
And I think, well, for instance, maybe, I mean they've
they've done some stuff around Chinese companies listing in the US,
and there's talk about maybe you stopped US investors from
investing in China.
Speaker 5 (19:29):
So that's the same thing as the Nixon playbook. That's
in the sixties. You're trying to push that offshore somewhere,
and so there will develop other financial centers and that
will take a while. It takes a while to develop,
but there are a number of competing financial centers. You know,
London was happy to take the euro dollar business. They
were like champion in the bed. We know how to
do this. We did this for Sterling. We just need
to change the little symbol in front and we can go.
(19:51):
You know, it took a while to make it all go.
It was the old guys who remembered, you know, and
they had to teach the young things. But the structure
was there, and so it could have and again, but
I'm just saying it's there now. You don't need to
build it. You don't need to build it. And so
I think that the chance that it's going to all
fall apart, okay, it's much bigger now, so that makes
it harder to manage, okay, But it also means that
(20:14):
it's evolved through crisis before from you know, every time
it's counted out, it's come back stronger, and not just stronger,
but expanding over the face of the globe that there
are these phases. You know, in ninety seventy one, it
was the US versus Europe. Okay. Then there's the Asian
financial crisis, which which I understand as the way we
were integrating Europe into the global dollar system that it
(20:36):
expanded and then you had to consolidate. Now it's gone
to the global South. We expanded and now we're in
consolidation phase. So I think we could come out of
this with a more robust system that's actually energetic and
has growth. But politics are the problem. You know, Are
the Americans going to be okay with this? You know?
Are the American political forces going to be okay with this?
(20:57):
Can a new political agreement between countries you know, be
made about this? And so that's where I'm out of
my depth. I don't really know. I don't really know.
What I have observed in life, okay, is that the
financial system sort of grows, grows, grows, grows, and then
the political system decides shall we bless this or shall
we kill it? You know, So there's a political settlement, okay,
(21:18):
and then you grow, grow, grow, grow, grow, and then
it happens again, you know. So that's how I see
what's happening now for me as a library rat as
I am, you know, there's just too much noise. I
don't know what's noise and what's signal at the moment.
So and I do think that this, you know, attempt
to play games with market valuations by announcing tariffs and
(21:38):
then taking them off but telling your friends beforehand, you know,
is very bad for market liquidity. You know, why would
you be a dealer to take the other side of
these trades, okay, if they're just going to take this
money away from you, you know. So I think that's
another place where there's stress in the system and pushback.
You noticed in the last week, you know, the lack
of liquidity and treasuries and things like that. I think
(21:58):
that's a lot of what that's about. Out It's that
the system seems to be rigged.
Speaker 4 (22:04):
Let's just talk about the events since April second for
a second, because the really and you alluded to it already,
But there's at least two dimensions. One is the sort
of pure economics of tariffs. It's a taxike. One useful
way to think about tariffs. Efforts to reassure manufacturing, perhaps
efforts to kneecap China specifically, and we don't know where
(22:27):
the tariffs are going to settle, and there's the final
relationship as the time we're recording this, and we may
never really know for the next four years. It seems plausible.
And then there's the politics, which you mentioned, which is
here you have a president who made a trade agreement
with Mexico and Canada, and suddenly it's like, maybe he
doesn't like it anymore, or he's willing to declare an
emergency to change the trading relationship with the rest of
(22:50):
the world.
Speaker 3 (22:51):
What's happening?
Speaker 4 (22:52):
And when I say what's happening, I mean is when
this all gets announced to your mind, what are the
first order effects of this sort of flurry of we're.
Speaker 3 (23:02):
Changing the rules right now?
Speaker 5 (23:04):
Well, I think the first art effects will be surprising, Okay.
I doubt that there's going to be much change in
net trade flows. That may be surprising to you, okay.
But what there's going to be is a change in
gross trade flows. Right This is a tax on trade
is essentially what it is, okay, So that there will
be less exports and less imports. The net is the
(23:26):
difference between those. So the net could stay the same
even as both exports and imports fall, and that will
be increasing inefficiency in global you know, division of labor.
So we're moving in the direction of autarchy. I don't
think we're going to get there completely because there's a
I mean, it's more possible for the United States because
it's a very big country. You know, there's almost everything
we need we have. It's cheaper from other places, you know,
(23:49):
but almost everything we need we have. It would take
a while to build up the capacity. And so this
is a very big country. But I think that this
is in fact killing global trade. That is very bad.
That's very bad for growth, that's very bad for people. Okay.
So I don't know what's going to happen to global
capital flows, okay, because, as I say, Kinderberger in the
(24:11):
seventies was surprised that capital flows actually continued even though
you were in a flexible exchange rate, because businesses were
looking through and saying, you know, this is a long
term investment. Exchange rates are moving this way that way.
I'm not thinking about that, okay. And there was some
backstop for short term bounds of payments, deficits and so
forth behind the scenes. So they sort of kept the
(24:34):
wheels from falling completely off the wagon in the seventies,
and as I say, I think there's even more capacity
to do that now. So I think the bottom line,
the most likely thing that's going to happen is that
just trade stops. I mean, I think people say, I
just listened to the news like you do, that essentially
there's a trade embargo in China right now, like there's
nothing is happening at all, and that's a pretty big
(24:56):
trading partner. So I mean, I don't know that that
will be the end result of this, you know, but
that's the immediate shock result of this. And I think
that if these tariffs were to persist, there would be much,
much less trade in the world economy, and that's not
good for ordinary people.
Speaker 1 (25:14):
Perry, Marilyn, thank you so much for coming back on again.
That was great.
Speaker 3 (25:17):
It's good to see you, Joe.
Speaker 1 (25:32):
It was great to catch up with Perry. Truly the
perfect guest.
Speaker 3 (25:35):
I love, I do love catching up with Perry.
Speaker 1 (25:37):
Yeah, And I mean, the analogy to the Nixon shock
seems to be one that people are reaching for over
and over again. And I guess I can see Perry's
point that there have been multiple instances where the dollar
system has been tested. Yeah, and it's sort of like
I don't know, a rubber ball that you like, stretch
and you test it and then it just like snaps
back to where it was, or it gets even bigger.
(25:58):
Right the dollars says done. And I guess the obvious
question is is it different this time?
Speaker 2 (26:04):
Right?
Speaker 4 (26:05):
I mean to me, like, you know, there's a few
different ideas here. So one is, you know, I think
it is useful to conceptualize the quote dollar system unquote
as this thing that exists independently of the United States government,
obviously through banks wanting to have you know, one medium
of exchange more or less, and global financial flows that
are everywhere. Then there is also this element and this
(26:26):
idea that you know, you could like tax trade and
you can have a shrinkage of trade, but that's not
necessarily going to make it so that there's a different
calculation about the global currency to use, et cetera. And
there's no obvious replacement just yet. All that being said,
like part of the reason this moment, and honestly before April,
second part of the reason this moment seems so fraught,
(26:49):
Perhaps to people is precisely because of the politics. Specifically
exactly which paracide you can't really talk to. But if
there's going to be some sort of real disruption, I
suspect it would from a political change rather than just
a change in fiscal policy.
Speaker 1 (27:04):
Right, And this is sort of the policy point. This
is exactly it. Whereas before I think everyone had like
a relatively decent or reasonable grasp of what policy makers
were trying to do. That seems very unclear, and we've
written about this in the newsletter. But if you think
about the dollar and dollar based assets as a sort
(27:26):
of symbol or token of America's rule of constitutional strength,
then it does seem different this time.
Speaker 3 (27:37):
Yeah, kind of does.
Speaker 1 (27:38):
Okay, So shall we leave it on that happy note.
Speaker 3 (27:41):
Let's leave it there.
Speaker 1 (27:41):
This has been another episode of the Odd Thoughts podcast.
I'm Tracy Alloway. You can follow me at Tracy Alloway.
Speaker 4 (27:47):
And I'm Jill Wisenthal. You can follow me at the Stalwart.
Check out our guest Perry Marling. He's at p Maryling.
Follow our producers Kerman Rodriguez at Kerman armand Dash, Will
Bennett at Dashbot and kill Brooks at kill Brooks for
more odd Laws content, go to Bloomberg dot com slash
odd Lots. We have all of our episodes in the
daily newsletter, and you can chet about all of these
topics twenty four to seven in our discord Discord dot
(28:09):
gg slash odd Lots.
Speaker 1 (28:10):
And if you enjoy odd Lots, if you like it
when we talk to Perry Merlin about Trump's playbook and
the Nixon Shock, then please leave us a positive review
on your favorite podcast platform. And remember, if you are
a Bloomberg subscriber, you can listen to all of our
episodes absolutely ad free. All you need to do is
find the Bloomberg channel on Apple Podcasts and follow the
instructions there. Thanks for listening.