Episode Transcript
Available transcripts are automatically generated. Complete accuracy is not guaranteed.
(00:00):
Welcome to the
(00:00):
Wealth Effect.
Today, we're talking about a phrase you
heard in your Econ 101 class and one of my
favorite economic concepts,
the invisible hand theorem.
The phrase invisible hand only shows
up three times in all of
Adam Smith's writings.
That's it.
Yet, it became a foundation for modern
economics, for free market theory,
(00:22):
for capitalism
itself.
But here's the thing.
Adam Smith wasn't
an economist first.
He was a moral*
philosopher.
In the theory of mortal sentiments,
and later in The Wealth of Nations,
Smith didn't argue that
markets make people good.
He argued that self-interest, when
(00:42):
channeled properly, can create outcomes
that serve society.
By pursuing his own interests, Smith
wrote, he frequently promotes that
of society more effectively than he
would really intends to promote it.
But the key
(01:02):
word here?
Frequently.
Not always.
Not eventually.
Adam Smith, a man of profound observation,
not blind faith, described this phenomenon
not as a mystical force, but as an
emergent property of human interaction,
(01:23):
when channeled through the right
structures, could lead
to collective benefit.
Another philosopher, Marcus Aurelius,
said, what is bad for the
hive is bad for the bee.
Let's begin with
the core principle.
It's about
self-interest.
The baker doesn't bake
bread out of charity.
(01:44):
He does it to
feed his family.
The butcher doesn't provide
meat out of benevolence.
He does it to
earn a living.
Yet, in pursuing these self-interested
goals, they provide goods that benefit the
entire community.
This is not a justification
for unchecked greed.
It's an observation.
(02:05):
Competition of
how systems work.
Competition is the regulator
that plays critical role in this.
If the baker charges exorbitant prices or
provides poor quality,
another baker will merge.
The market, in its own way, disciplines
those who seek to exploit it.
(02:26):
The invisible hand is a manifestation of
disorder, a complex system that emerges
from simple
interactions.
But systems can be
corrupt and manipulated.
When power becomes concentrated,
when competition is hindered, the
invisible hand becomes
(02:46):
a tool of oppression.
Understanding the invisible hand is
not about blindly trusting the market.
It's about understanding its
strengths and its weaknesses.
It's about recognizing
the systems.
It's about recognizing that individual
actions have consequences, that our
choices, however small,
(03:06):
contribute to the larger whole.
So what does this
mean for you?
It means this.
Your business doesn't just succeed
by trying to serve society.
It succeeds by serving yourself in a
way that ends up benefiting others.
Let's say you
make software.
You don't build it
to save the world.
You build it because you
(03:26):
want to solve a problem.
And people will
pay for it.
But if it's truly
useful, it does both.
It makes you rich
and improves lives.
That's the invisible
hand at work.
But only if you're
playing the long game.
Only if you're building
value and not extracting it.
(03:47):
The system you build matters
more than your intentions.
We all know that someone who meant well,
but built a business that
ended up hurting people.
Or someone who chased profits and by
accident built a company that changed
lives forever.
That's the paradox of
the invisible hand.
(04:07):
It doesn't care about
your mission statement.
It responds
to incentives.
Think about
Patagonia.
They sell clothes, but they built a
system that rewards sustainability.
Think about Costco.
Low prices, high
wages, loyal customers.
That's not charity.
That's a strategy.
Great entrepreneurs don't
(04:28):
just solve problems.
They build systems.
The invisible hand
isn't a force of nature.
It's a metaphor for what happens when we
design systems where doing well and doing
good are the
same thing.
Thank you for
listening.
Until next time.