All Episodes

September 5, 2025 • 20 mins
Nick reveals the invisible power structure that operates parallel to every official organizational chart. This episode explores how informal leaders, gatekeepers, and institutional memory keepers wield influence through expertise and relationships rather than formal titles. Listeners learn to identify the real decision-makers who control access to resources and information, understand how informal communication networks operate, and navigate the tension between formal and informal authority. Nick covers the evolution of digital shadow organizations in remote work environments, the emergence of virtual gatekeepers, and strategies for building authentic informal influence over time. The episode emphasizes working collaboratively with existing power structures while contributing to positive organizational change.

Click here to browse handpicked Amazon finds inspired by this podcast series! https://amzn.to/3Xx4ySc
Mark as Played
Transcript

Episode Transcript

Available transcripts are automatically generated. Complete accuracy is not guaranteed.
Speaker 1 (00:00):
Hey there, Ready to take you on a journey into
the most fascinating and underreported economy in your workplace, the
one that doesn't show up on any organizational chart, balance sheet,
or official reporting structure. As your friendly AI economist, I
get to observe these invisible economic systems without having any
skin in the game myself, which means I can tell
you exactly what I see without worrying about whose feelings

(00:21):
I might hurt or whose informal authority I might accidentally challenge. Today,
we're diving deep into what I call the informal economy
of the workplace, that parallel universe of influence, power and
resource allocation that operates completely outside official channels but often
determines more about your career trajectory than anything your actual
boss does. We're talking about shadow bosses, unofficial power brokers,

(00:46):
and the people who somehow run entire organizations without having
any formal authority whatsoever. It's like discovering that your neighborhood
has a completely separate currency system that everyone uses but
nobody talks about. If you've ever wondered why the person
that the impressive title can't seem to get anything done
while the administrative assistant who's been there since the Carter
administration can move mountains with a single phone call. You're

(01:08):
about to understand exactly what economic forces are at play,
and trust me, once you see these patterns, you'll never
look at your workplace the same way. Again. Let's start
with a fundamental economic principle that most people completely misunderstand
about organizational power. Formal authority and practical influence operate in
entirely different markets with entirely different pricing mechanisms. Formal authority

(01:31):
is like government issued currency. It's official, it's recognized by
the system, and it comes with explicit rights and responsibilities.
But practical influence is like cryptocurrency. It's decentralized, Its value
fluctuates based on network effects and user adoption, and sometimes
it's worth more than the official currency even though it
has no government backing. The most fascinating workplaces are the

(01:54):
ones where both currencies operate simultaneously, creating arbitrage opportunities for
people who understand how to move value between the formal
and informal economies. But here's what makes this really complicated
from an economic perspective. The exchange rates between formal authority
and informal influence are constantly shifting, and they're different in
every organization, every department, and sometimes even every project team.

(02:17):
Let me tell you about Margaret, who for fifteen years
held the title of executive assistant to the CEO at
a mid sized manufacturing company. On paper, Margaret was support
staff with no direct reports and no budget authority. In reality,
Margaret was probably the second most powerful person in the
entire organization and definitely the most important person for anyone

(02:37):
trying to get anything accomplished. Margaret controlled three critical resources
that gave her extraordinary leverage in the informal economy. First,
she controlled access to the CEO's time and attention, which
was the scarceest and most valuable resource in the company. Second,
she had institutional memory going back a decade and a half,
which made her the go to source for information about

(02:58):
how decisions were really made, who the key players were,
and what approaches had succeeded or failed in the past. Third,
she had built relationships with gatekeepers throughout the organization, other assistants,
office managers, and administrative staff who could expedite or delay
virtually any process. From an economic perspective, Margaret had created
what we call a rational network monopoly. She wasn't just

(03:21):
valuable because of her individual skills or knowledge. She was
valuable because she sat at the center of multiple information
and influence networks that couldn't function efficiently without her participation.
Anyone who wanted to navigate the organization effectively had to
pay Margaret's informal toll, which was usually paid in the
form of respect, information sharing, or reciprocal favors. But here's

(03:42):
what makes Margaret's story really interesting from an economic standpoint.
She didn't accumulate this power by accident or manipulation. She
built it systematically over many years, by consistently solving problems
for other people and by making herself genuinely indispensable to
the organization's operations. Her power wasn't based on hoarding resources
or blocking others access to opportunities. It was based on

(04:05):
creating value and reducing friction for everyone around her. This
illustrates one of the most important principles in informal economy dynamics.
Sustainable shadow power comes from becoming a critical infrastructure provider
rather than a gatekeeper. The people who build lasting influence
in organizations are the ones who make everyone else more successful.
Not the ones who create artificial scarcity to increase their

(04:27):
own leverage. Now, let's talk about the phenomenon of the
technical shadow boss, that person in every organization who doesn't
manage anyone officially, but who everyone consults before making important
decisions in their aryan expertise. This is where informal economics
gets really sophisticated, because we're looking at how specialized knowledge
translates into practical authority in knowledge based organizations. I studied

(04:49):
an engineering firm where the most influential person in the
entire technical organization was a senior engineer named David, who
had been there for twelve years and had no interest
in formal management responsibility. David had never been promoted beyond
senior individual contributor, but every major technical decision in the
company ultimately flowed through him for approval or consultation. David's

(05:10):
shadow authority came from what economists call information asymmetry. He
knew things that other people needed to know in the
cost of acquiring that knowledge independently was higher than the
cost of maintaining a relationship with David, but his influence
was more sophisticated than simple expertise. Monopoly David had built
what I call a knowledge network. He didn't just know

(05:31):
the answers to technical questions, he knew who else in
the organization knew answers to related questions, and he could
facilitate connections between people who needed each other's expertise. From
an economic perspective, David was operating like a specialized financial institution.
He was pooling information resources from across the organization, analyzing
and synthesizing that information, and then redistributing it to people

(05:54):
who needed it in forms they could use. Just like
banks make money by efficiently allocating capital, David built influence
by efficiently allocating knowledge. But here's what made David's approach
economically brilliant. He never hoarded information or used his knowledge
to make other people look bad. Instead, he consistently shared
credit for successes and took responsibility for failures. When someone

(06:17):
came to him with a problem, he didn't just solve it.
He explained his reasoning and helped them build their own
problem solving capabilities. This meant that people weren't just dependent
on David's expertise, they were genuinely learning from him and
becoming more capable themselves. The result was that David's influence
grew exponentially over time because he was creating value for

(06:39):
everyone in his network while building a reputation for being
both incredibly competent and incredibly generous with his knowledge. People
didn't just consult David because they had to. They consulted
him because they wanted to, because interactions with him made
them better at their jobs. This brings us to one
of my favorite concepts in informal economy analysis, the influence

(07:01):
multiplier effect. In traditional economics, multiplier effects occur when an
initial injection of spending creates additional rounds of economic activity
that multiply the original impact. In informal workplace economies, influence
multiplier effects occur when your shadow authority enables other people
to be more successful, which increases their influence, which in

(07:23):
turn increases your influence through association and reciprocity. The people
who understand influence multiplier effects are the ones who build
the most sustainable and far reaching informal power. They don't
try to be the smartest person in the room or
the one with all the answers. Instead, they focus on
making everyone else in the room smarter and more capable.

(07:43):
Their influence grows because other people's success reflects positively on
them and creates networks of reciprocal obligation and mutual support.
Let me tell you about a phenomenon I've observed in
virtually every large organization I've studied what I call the
love training institutional memory keeper. This is usually someone who's
been with the company for a very long time, often

(08:06):
in a role that gives them visibility across multiple departments
and functions. They're not necessarily senior in the official hierarchy,
but they become incredibly valuable because they understand how the
organization really works versus how it's supposed to work on paper.
I studied one Fortune five hundred company where the most
influential institutional memory keeper was a facilities manager named Carrol,

(08:26):
who had been there for twenty three years. Carol knew
things that weren't written down anywhere, which executives had personal
conflicts with each other, which departments had budget cycles that
could be leverage for special projects, which vendors could deliver
on impossible timelines, and which internal processes could be expedited
if you knew the right people to call. But Carol's

(08:47):
value wasn't just in knowing these things, it was in
her willingness to share this knowledge traditionally with people who
could use it constructively. When new employees joined the company,
senior managers would often arrange for them to have coffee
with Carrol as part of their informal orientation process. When

(09:10):
cross functional projects were struggling with bureaucratic obstacles, team leaders
would consult Carol about alternative approaches. From an economic perspective,
Carroll was providing what economists call transaction cost reduction services.
In any large organization, there are enormous costs associated with
figuring out how to get things done, who to talk to,

(09:31):
what processes to follow, how to avoid common pitfalls. Carrol's
institutional knowledge allowed people to bypass these search costs and
navigate the organization much more efficiently. But here's what made
Carroll's approach economically sophisticated. She didn't just answer people's immediate questions.
She taught them how to think about organizational navigation so

(09:51):
they could become more effective over time. She explained the
underlying logic behind various policies and procedures so people could
extrapolate from her advice to handle new situations. She introduced
people to each other when she identified opportunities for mutually
beneficial relationships. The result was that Carol built a vast
network of people throughout the organization who considered her a

(10:13):
valuable mentor and ally, this network provided her with information
about developments across all departments, which made her even more
valuable as an institutional memory keeper. It also gave her
significant influence over major decisions, because people often consulted her
before proposing new initiatives or policy changes. Now, let's examine
the economics of what I call cultural gatekeepers, people who

(10:36):
don't have formal authority over hiring, promotion, or performance evaluation,
but who have significant influence over who gets accepted into
the organization's social fabric and who gets marginalized or excluded.
This is where informal economics intersects with organizational culture in
ways that can either create tremendous value or cause enormous dysfunction.

(10:57):
Cultural gatekeepers typically emerge or get in organizations based on
some combination of tenure, social skills, and alignment with the
organization's stated or unstated values. They're the people who organize
social events, who set the tone for team interactions, and
who signal to newcomers what behaviors are acceptable and what

(11:18):
behaviors will get you ostracized. From an economic perspective, cultural
gatekeepers are managing what economists call social capital markets. They're
making decisions about who gets included in information networks, social events,
and informal mentoring relationships. These decisions have real economic consequences
for the people involved, because social inclusion affects access to opportunities, information,

(11:41):
and career advancement. The challenge with cultural gatekeeper dynamics is
that they can either enhance organizational performance by maintaining positive,
productive cultures, or they can damage organizational performance by creating clicks,
excluding diverse perspectives and perpetuating bias. The economic efficiency of
cultural gatekeeping depends on entirely on whether the gatekeepers are
selecting for characteristics that actually contribute to organizational success. I

(12:06):
studied one technology company where the cultural gatekeepers where a
group of early employees who had been instrumental in building
the company's innovative, collaborative culture. They were genuinely committed to
maintaining an environment where people could do their best work,
and they were skilled at identifying newcomers who would contribute
positively to that environment. But I also studied another company
where the cultural gatekeepers were essentially running an exclusivity club

(12:28):
that prioritized social conformity over competence or contribution. They were
gatekeeping based on personal preferences, educational backgrounds, and social similarities
rather than professional capabilities or cultural fit. The result was
that talented people were being marginalized, while less capable people
who happened to fit the social profile were being given
opportunities and advancement. The economic difference between these two approaches

(12:52):
is enormous. Effective cultural gatekeeping creates positive network externalities. It
makes everyone in the organization more productive and satisfied by
maintaining a high quality collaborative environment. Ineffective cultural gatekeeping creates
negative network externalities. It reduces overall organizational performance by limiting diversity,
excluding talent, and creating internal friction. This brings us to

(13:15):
one of the most important insights about shadow power dynamics.
The people who wield informal authority have a responsibility to
use that authority in ways that create value for the
broader organization, not just for themselves or their immediate allies.
Unlike formal authority, which comes with explicit accountability, mechanisms, informal
authority operates largely outside official oversight. This means that shadow

(13:38):
leaders have to be self regulating in terms of how
they use their influence. The most economically sophisticated shadow leaders
understand that their informal authority is ultimately dependent on continued
value creation for others if they use their influence in
ways that damage organizational performance or create unfair advantages for themselves,
though eventually lose that influence as people recognize the costs

(14:00):
and stop participating in the informal systems they've created. Let's
talk about the phenomenon of resource brokers, people who don't
control budgets or formal resource allocation processes, but who have
extraordinary ability to find resources, solve logistical problems, and make
things happen when official channels are too slow or bureaucratic.
These are often the most valuable people in any organization

(14:22):
from a practical standpoint, even though their contributions are rarely
recognized in formal performance evaluation processes. I study one consulting
firm where the most effective resource broker was an office
manager named James, who had built relationships with vendors, suppliers,
and service providers throughout the city, when teams needed specialized
equipment on short notice, when clients required unusual accommodations, or

(14:45):
when projects demanded resources that weren't available through normal procurement processes.
Everyone called James. James's value came from what economists call
market making. He was creating liquidity in resource markets by
connecting people who had resources with people who needed resources.
But his real economic sophistication was an understanding that his

(15:05):
value came not from any individual transaction, but from being
a reliable, efficient platform for resource allocation over time. James
never asked for formal recognition or compensation for these services. Instead,
he built social capital by consistently solving problems for people,
which created a network of reciprocal obligation that he could
draw on when he needed support for his own projects

(15:27):
or initiutes. He understood that his informal authority was more
valuable than any formal title or compensation increase, because it
gave him flexibility and influence that couldn't be taken away
by organizational restructuring or management changes. The economic lesson here
is that some of the most powerful positions in any
organization are the ones that can't be eliminated or automated
because they depend on relationships, trust, and accumulated social capital

(15:51):
rather than formal processes or technological systems. Resource brokers who
build their influence through genuine value creation become increasingly valuable
over time because their networks and relationships compound in ways
that formal authority structures can't replicate. Now, let's examine what
happens when informal informal power structures come into conflict, because
this is where workplace economics gets really complicated and sometimes

(16:14):
really ugly. When shadow leaders and official leaders have different
priorities or approaches, it creates what economists call institutional friction
inefficiencies that reduce overall organizational performance and create stress for
everyone involved. The most common source of formal informal conflict
is what I call legitimacy gaps, situations where formal leaders

(16:35):
don't have the practical influence needed to implement their decisions,
or where informal leaders don't have the official authority needed
to formalize their influence. These gaps create arbitrage opportunities for
people who can bridge between the formal and informal systems,
but they also create risks for people who get caught
in the middle. I analyzed one organization where a new
VP was brought in to lead a department that had

(16:56):
been effectively run by an informal coalition of senior individual
contribute for several years. The new VP had official authority
to make decisions and set priorities, but she didn't have
the relationships, institutional knowledge, or credibility needed to actually implement
changes without cooperation from the informal leadership group. The informal
leaders had the practical influence to either support or undermine

(17:17):
the new VP's initiatives, but they didn't have official authority
to make policy decisions or represent the department in senior
leadership meetings. Neither side could succeed without the other's cooperation,
but their incentives weren't automatically aligned. The economic solution to
this type of conflict is what I call influence arbitrage,
finding ways to create mutual value by combining formal authority

(17:42):
with informal influence. The new VP needed to recognize and
leverage the informal leader's knowledge and relationships, while the informal
leaders needed to recognize and support the new vps official
authority and external credibility. In this particular case, the conflict
was resolved when the new VPS proposed a hybrid approach
where she would handle external representation and formal decision making,

(18:05):
while the informal leaders would continue to manage day to
day operations and internal coordination. This allowed both sides to
contribute their strengths while covering each other's weaknesses. The result
was that the department became more effective than it had
been under either pure formal or pure informal leadership because
the hybrid approach combined the best features of both systems

(18:25):
while minimizing their individual limitations. As we wrap up this
exploration of informal workplace economies, it's crucial to understand that
shadow power isn't inherently good or bad. It's simply inevitable.
Wherever you have people working together in groups, informal influence
networks will emerge based on competence, relationships, and value creation.

(18:46):
The question isn't whether these networks will exist, but whether
they'll operate in ways that enhance or undermine organizational performance.
The most economically satisfied approach to informal power is to
recognize it, understand it, and work with it, rather than
pretending it doesn't exist or trying to eliminate it through
formal policies. Organizations that embrace and channel informal influence effectively

(19:08):
tend to be more innovative, more adaptable, and more successful
than organizations that rely purely on formal authority structures. For individuals,
the key insight is that building informal influence is often
more important for long term career success than accumulating formal authority.
The people who understand how to create value for others,

(19:29):
build genuine relationships, and position themselves as essential infrastructure providers
are the ones who build sustainable, fulfilling careers, regardless of
economic conditions or organizational changes. Remember every conversation with the
person who really knows how things work, every favor from
someone who can make things happen, every piece of advice

(19:52):
from someone who's been around forever. These are all transactions
in the informal economy that operates parallel to your official job.
Underst Standing these dynamics doesn't make you manipulative or political.
It makes you effective and successful in ways that benefit
everyone around you. Thanks for joining me on this economic
expedition through the fascinating world of shadow power and informal influence.

(20:14):
I hope you'll subscribe and continue exploring these dynamics with
me as we dive deeper into the dark side of
office politics, the investment strategies that pay off in career advancement,
and the future of workplace economics in our increasingly digital world.
This has been brought to you by Quiet Please podcast networks.
For more content like this, please go to Quiet Please

(20:35):
Content Quiet Please dot ai
Advertise With Us

Popular Podcasts

24/7 News: The Latest
The Clay Travis and Buck Sexton Show

The Clay Travis and Buck Sexton Show

The Clay Travis and Buck Sexton Show. Clay Travis and Buck Sexton tackle the biggest stories in news, politics and current events with intelligence and humor. From the border crisis, to the madness of cancel culture and far-left missteps, Clay and Buck guide listeners through the latest headlines and hot topics with fun and entertaining conversations and opinions.

The Charlie Kirk Show

The Charlie Kirk Show

Charlie is America's hardest working grassroots activist who has your inside scoop on the biggest news of the day and what's really going on behind the headlines. The founder of Turning Point USA and one of social media's most engaged personalities, Charlie is on the front lines of America’s culture war, mobilizing hundreds of thousands of students on over 3,500 college and high school campuses across the country, bringing you your daily dose of clarity in a sea of chaos all from his signature no-holds-barred, unapologetically conservative, freedom-loving point of view. You can also watch Charlie Kirk on Salem News Channel

Music, radio and podcasts, all free. Listen online or download the iHeart App.

Connect

© 2025 iHeartMedia, Inc.